Introduction
A 2002 policy
paper, outlined a vision of National Value added tax (NATVAT) that it suggested
could be put in place by 2010 through a constitutional amendment, after creating genuine Central VAT (CENVAT) and States VATs (STATVAT) within the existing constitutional limits.[i]
Given the degree of interest in the Goods and Service Tax (GST) among industry,
financial participants, economists and the general public, a version of the
NATVAT, which differs somewhat from the GST
is outlined below. The two differ
in relatively minor but critically important details. In my view these difference would have made
it easier to get political acceptability for the NATVAT from States.
Indirect Taxes
Tax theory provides us a number of insights into the
nature of indirect taxes that are best for a country. The most important insight is that there
should effectively be no tax (i.e. zero rate) on raw materials, intermediate
goods, capital goods and services used for production of goods &
services. The second insight is that
efficiency considerations drive the differentiated structure of consumer taxes
towards higher rates on goods & services with low demand elasticity. In the case of de-merit goods like cigarettes
& tobacco products and (perhaps) hard liquor this proves easy to
apply. However, as necessities have
lower elasticity of demand than luxuries this runs contrary to the equity
objectives that tend to drive the tax structure in the opposite direction
(assuming a reasonably strong desire for social equity as commonly professed in
India). The net result depends on the
detailed elasticity.
There are two other lessons that involve a greater element of
judgement: That efficiency and equity
considerations tend to balance each other and that a near-uniform structure of
indirect taxes may be a useful starting point for a reasonably efficient and
equitable tax system. Another is that
there is a case for taxing at a somewhat higher rate goods & services that
are complementary with leisure (e.g. goods & service for entertainment),
though the force of this argument is diluted in a large population countries
(like India) with substantial or ‘hidden unemployment’ or ‘under-employment.
Why VAT
This is the appropriate point in which to bring in the problems of
tax administration, evasion and corruption that loom so large in developing
countries (emerging markets) and which this theoretical exercise has totally
ignored. Logically the structure of
optimal taxes based on reality (varying administrative costs, evasion costs
& corruption possibilities) would differ markedly from that given by the
“ideal.” There is wide agreement among tax experts who advise governments on
tax reform that these problems argue strongly for having an indirect tax
structure that is simple and as close to uniformity as possible. Complexity facilitates and encourages tax
evasion and corruption. It also provides
an incentive for lobbying by powerful organised groups to obtain special favours
for themselves. This sets in motion a
spiral of complexity, evasion & corruption that is not based on any
empirical knowledge (of elasticity) and results in a tax structure that bears
no relationship to the so-called ideal “optimal.”
The
second implication of this reality (administrative costs, evasion, corruption)
is that the best way to implement a uniform structure of indirect taxes is
through a value added tax. A uniform
value added tax (VAT) has the same efficiency & equity properties as a
uniform sales tax on final finished consumer goods, but by collecting the tax
at multiple points and in smaller doses it minimises the incentive for
evasion. It also has (in principle &
if implemented properly) the property of catching at a later stage the tax
evasion that has taken place at earlier stages of production/ value added. These considerations have led an overwhelming
majority of countries (not just developing but even developed) to replace their
existing indirect taxes by a Value Added Tax.
An indirect tax structure for the country (Centre & States) that
will be simple, efficient and equitable should ideally replace all central and
state government taxes on goods and services.
National VAT
An ideal indirect structure for the country would consist of two
sets of indirect taxes: A single uniform rate National VAT on all
goods and services (except for a limited number of pre-specified exemptions)
and State (final) sales taxes on a dozen specified goods with a pre-specified
upper limit on the sales tax rate for each of these goods. The Central government would have the
responsibility of setting the national VAT rate in consultation with the States
and for administering it with the help of the States as needed. Calculations done in the 2000s suggested that
a VAT of 15% may be sufficient to ensure revenue neutrality with respect to
existing Central & State indirect taxes.
The proceeds from this tax would be shared between the Central
government and the States in the proportion necessary to ensure that there is
no diminution of the States’ indirect tax revenues. To ensure that the indirect system is
equitable, and to support positive externalities, the following goods and
services could be exempt from the VAT: Food, including processed (cereals,
pulses, vegetables, fruits, milk & products and possibly sugar), Drugs,
Medical Equipment & medical services (Diagnostic; Disability compensating
or Disease preventing/curing), Environment friendly fuels (solar), Educational
services and Knowledge services (Educational material, R&D, Testing,
Consultancy). There would also be a
sales volume exemption of Rs. 5 lakh (say) based solely on the need for
minimising compliance & administrative costs. All other exemptions should be
abolished. Administration of the system
for transactions up to some limit (Rs. 10/20 lakh say) could perhaps be
decentralised to the States. States would also have to abolish Octroi one of the most inefficient taxes know,
Final Sales Taxes
In addition, the State government would have the right to levy sales
taxes on a limited set of final, finished consumer goods (to ensure that there
is no cascading & no taxation of intermediate goods). The maximum total tax on any good or service
should not exceed 50%. At this point, the incentive for tax evasion becomes so
strong that corruption is sure to follow. This means that with a VAT rate of
15%, the sales tax must not exceed 35% (upper limit/maximum). Such a high rate could however be applied
only to de-merit goods such as tobacco products (cigarettes, cigars, chewing
tobacco) and hard liquor. Fuels with
negative environmental externality, such as petrol & diesel, could be
subject to a maximum sales tax of 25%.
The same maximum rate could also apply to cars and low (< 5%)
alcohol beverages like beer & wine.
A few other items such as Air travel, Air Conditioners, Motor
cycles/scooters & home entertainment products (excluding radio & TV),
Entertainment services like cinema, Hotels & Restaurants service, could be
subject to a maximum sales tax of 15% (i.e. 0% to 15%), as the VAT would
replace the existing set of entertainment taxes, expenditure tax, sales tax
etc.
Across the world, Sales taxes
are normally levied at the point of sale to the consumer. Because of evasion & related problems, India
follows the practice of “first point sales tax,” where the tax is collected at
the point of sale by the producer.
Strictly speaking this is better termed as an excise tax. However, as long as cascading and multiple
taxation are avoided and all States follow the same method, either method can
be adopted. Both the national VAT and the State Sales taxes would apply to
imported consumer goods & services in the same way as they do to
domestically produced ones. The final
point of sale collection (of sales tax) has the merit that each State can
collect its own sales tax on imported goods.
If the first point Sales tax (excise) methodology is adopted then an
excise/sales/SAD tax will also have to be collected (on the specified set of
goods) at the customs point on behalf of the States. This creates undue complexity if the States
have different rates of tax on the same good. Imported goods would enter the
VAT chain at the point of entry into the country and from there on be treated
exactly as if they had been produced in India.
Administration & Evasion
The single rate NATVAT allows a drastic
simplification in administration & compliance, which is the great advantage of a true VAT. This simplification is based on a complete
transformation of the collection and administration machinery. It has the following related elements:
·
An invoice and accounts based system of checking
in place of routine physical checking.
·
Basic data on the company (and its production
units, warehouses, depots etc) would be entered once given an appropriate code
number (VAN on the lines of PAN) and stored on the computer. It would not
have to be entered on every invoice as at present.
·
A simplified invoice form that focuses on values of inputs and outputs subject to the
single VAT rate, and the source and destination of the inputs and outputs
respectively (again represented by VAN).
This is most effective if there is a single uniform base NATVAT rate
with all goods treated equally on both the input and output side with respect
to this rate. In this case the sale or
invoice form would only require the total value of goods sold and the code
number (VAN) of the originating and destination units.
·
Monthly, quarterly or annual aggregation of the
sales and purchase slips depending on volume of business (i.e. SSI have to do
only annual aggregation, and only the largest units have to do monthly
aggregation). The aggregation would
involve showing total value of purchases and sales by seller & buyer
respectively, during the relevant period.
·
A comprehensive computerisation of these
aggregate returns, which allow cross checking of inputs, outputs value added
and CENVAT paid, so as to detect evasion. Direct e- filing could be required
for VAT payers above a certain size (Rs. 10 crore say).
·
This could be supplemented by industry wide
database, which can be used to identify flow of goods and services entirely
outside the VAT chain.
Conclusion
In
comparison to a Goods and Services Tax (GST) as proposed, the National VAT
(NATVAT) greatly simplifies administration of the national system of indirect
taxes, and would help in drastically reducing tax evasion. At the same time
gives some flexibility to states to levy a half a dozen final sales taxes, so
that they can meet fluctuations in revenues and expenditure by varying some
taxes under their direct control.
[i]
Arvind Virmani, “Towards a Competitive Economy: VAT and Customs Duty
Reform,” Planning Commission Working Paper No. 4/2002-PC, April 2002. http://www.planningcommission.nic.in/reports/wrkpapers/wp_vat
The GST Structure includes a tax on central goods and services, tax on government goods and services, tax on integrated goods and services, and tax on Union territory goods and services. There are four slab levels ranging from 5% to 28%, with the lowest being essential items and the highest being luxury goods.
ReplyDeleteIf you are living in Singapore and if you need any help from maids and you are finding the best maid agency for hiring a maid in singapore at that moment universal employment agency will be the best option for you. So, try your best to hire the maid from there because that place also cost very reasonable that you can't believe until you go for hiring them.
ReplyDeleteThanks for sharing such a nice piece of information with us regarding Value added tax in Oman
ReplyDeleteCool! Thanks for sharing the information on Value Added Tax. To get registered: Online GST Registration
ReplyDeletevat solution
ReplyDeleteVAT is essentially a consumption tax levied at every stage of the supply chain (added on the value added to goods and services) – from raw materials to the end product. It importantly serves as a source of revenue for governments.
Such an appreciable answer on value-added tax and you can apply here for GST Registration online.
ReplyDelete