Tuesday, August 30, 2011

Comment on "So-called export led growth", by Jie Yang, IMF WP/08/220

Yang has a different definition of “export led ” than one has always used (which one always thought was the standard one). Our definition is in terms of policy bias ( tax-subsidy, exchange rate) towards exports as against a tax-subsidy-exchange regime that is neutral between imports and exports.  The question is whether government deliberately attempts to promote exports (through fair and foul means) or has a neutral policy regime!   The second stage of this analysis is to see which of the export oriented regimes were successful in raising export growth and GDP growth.  Those that are successful would be termed as following an export led growth strategy, regardless of what happens to the exchange rate!  In fact a depreciation of the exchange rate may be a precursor to or part and parcel of a biased policy regime promoting exports.  In fact the time pattern would be important. For instance successful high growth countries may gradually move from export bias to a neutral policy regime, with depreciation in the former period and appreciation thereafter, where the latter is an outcome of the success of the earlier policy!
    
Productivity increases will result in the Balassa-Samuelson effect (tradable productivity growth higher -> appreciation) and inverse Balassa-Samuelson effect (non-tradable prdoctivity growth higher -> depreciation) depending on which sector has faster productivity change.  An interesting emperical observation in the paper is that about half the high growth economies (as per Yang's definition) had an appreciation while a smaller number had a depreciation.  This aspect needs to be investigated further however, by relating it to the policy regime they had (in terms of export bias) and the time pattern of exchange rate changes.

Friday, August 26, 2011

Fiscal Debt Sustainability

In my 25 years of interaction with multilateral financial institutions on fiscal issues, I have repeatedly made the following points (which remain valid till today): 1) That the simple rule that growth rate must be more than the real interest rate is a good guide to ensuring that debt GDP ratio declines over time. (2) Theory does not tell us what level of the debt-GDP ratio is optimal. A number of factors are important for judging whether this level is too high. Among these are, (a) The asset owned or the net debt-GDP ratio. In other words a country with a lower debt, net of assets, can sustain a higher gross debt-GDP ratio.  Given the financial innovation over the last 25 years, it is also necessary to emphasise that the liquidity, maturity structure and uncertainty/risk associated with the assets also matters! A further implication is that debt incurred for investment is more sustainable than if used for consumption and transfers. (b) The manner of financing of the debt, in particular the proportion financed by domestic as against foreign capita/savings.  Thus countries with higher private domestic saving rates can sustain a higher level of debt to GDP and vice versa! (c) The demand conditions in the economy relative to potential supply.  An economy sufferring from lack of effective demand (virtually all advanced economies today), need to balance policy measure to ensure medium-long run debt reduction, with investment in public and quasi public goods in the short run to ensure effective demand.  If this is not done, growth will suffer and debt-GDP ratios will end up higher than they could be!  However, in economies suffering from excess demand (several Emerging economies today) and inflation, immediate fiscal (expenditure) contraction can allow a more relaxed monetary policy that will sustain growth and accelerate debt reduction. 

Wednesday, August 17, 2011

Emerging Economies need Domestic Reforms

In June this year, I concluded that the USA and EU were heading towards a lost decade, because their political systems had kept them dealing fully with the financial crises (web site).  The social-political developments in Italy and the US since then have raised the risks of a double dip.  Given this background can the Emerging economies (China, India, Brazil, Russia et al) maintain the growth differential? My answer is, 'Yes, if they take urgent steps to remove domestic constraint to growth and to stimulate domestic drivers of growth.' For China this means re-orienting its economy towards lower party-State controlled profits, higher wages and private consumption, greater public expenditures on social services (as against manufacturing investment) and slower export growth-appreciated exchange rate.  For India it means a faster reduction of the fiscal deficit, and a step-up of the pace of policy-regulatory reforms. In particular four broad reform areas have the potential of both accelerating growth and reducing inequality: (1) Urban planning, land use and urban infrastructure(water, sewage, public transport, parking), (2) Food supply chain modernization (FDI in retail trade). (3) Oil-energy policy and regulation (price distorting to direct  subsidies, regulated benchmark competition in electricity). (4) Skill development founded on high quality basic education (3 R s).  Similarly, if  Brazil, Russia, Indonesia and other large EMs can put their domestic house in order, they can collectively survive the growth slowdown and heightened risk emanating from the USA and Europe    

Tuesday, August 16, 2011

Socio-political Warning

For those of us familiar with country ratings based on fiscal situation and fiscal politics of emerging and developing countries the downgrade of US rating by S&P was surprising only to the extent that a US rating agency dared to be even handed and dared to apply to the US, the same rules and procedures that they had always applied to emerging economies (EMs):  That political inaction or gridlock about fiscal reform  is not a valid argument against a rating downgrade.  Nevertheless this downgrade is warning not only to the political systems of the US and the Euro area/European Union, but also for the emerging economies and developing countries.  That is, to use the relative good economic situation that still prevails in these countries to reduce fiscal deficits and put sovereign debt: GDP ratios on a downward trend, before the heightened risk of a European crisis triggers a double dip in the US and affects the EMDCs.  Such a crisis, however low the probability, will leave little room for manouver for those EMs that do not take pre-emptive action to reduce deficits, remove domestic bottlenecks to growth and undertake reforms to activate growth drivers.  For instance, the Indian economic survey 2008-9 (DEA, MOF) give a menu of 6 boxes, including fiscal reforms, that should be carried out to ensure that the growth rate does not decline below the potential of 8.5 to 9%.  Unfortunately these warnings the pace of reforms has slowed below the average trend seen in the previous two decades.  If the pace of reforms is not restored back to its trend, the rate of growth is likely to decline gradually, given the dire global economic outlook and heightened global risks

Thursday, August 11, 2011

Financial Crises Stage 2

The financial turmoil following S&Ps downgrade of US debt, publicly signals the onset of stage 2 of the US-European financial crisis. It is also a wake up call to these countries' socio-political system, which has failed to fully deal with the policy reform issues thrown up by the financial crisis. One has repeatedly pointed out over the past 18 months (within the international institution with which one is associated) some of the critical issues (e.g. US household mortgage debt problem or the solvency issue in 3-4 euro countries) that were not being addressed and others which were being wrongly addressed (the focus on sharp instant expenditure cuts vs. legally and institutionally sustainable reduction in expenditure). However, it is only over the last few months one had come to the conclusion that given the political gridlock in the USA and political constraints in the Euro area, these two regions are likely to see a lost decade analogous to Japan. In this context, I view the S&P down grade as a 'wake up call' to the political systems of these two economies to resolve the policy stasis if they want their economies to recover at a pace faster than the 7-10 years of previous financial crisis. This requires policy intervention to accelerate household mortgage debt de-leveraging and a solution to the solvency problem through contributions from the debtors and stronger Euro countries.